The Gods of Eden - Chapter 21: Funny Money

Rick
Rick
Last updated 
image.png 1.82 MB View full-size Download


FEW TOPICS OCCUPY as many minds or stimulate as many emotions as money.

Pink Floyd - Money (Official Music Video)


This is largely because money is an overwhelming problem to a majority of people.

What if EVERYONE Was Wealthy Beyond Their Wildest Dreams? – Library of Rickandria

One thing which causes modern money to be a problem is inflation, whether inflation is climbing at 3% annually or 300%.

Inflation, of course, is the situation in which the costs of goods and services steadily rise due to the ever-decreasing value of money.

This happens when the money supply becomes larger in proportion to the supply of valuable goods and services.

Money itself is not valuable; only the goods and services that can be bought with it are.

The wealth of any individual or nation, therefore, is ultimately determined by what it produces in terms of valuable products and services, not by how much money it:


  • prints
  • distributes
  • holds

A nation could actually survive without any currency at all as long as it was otherwise productive.

The purpose of money is to facilitate the exchange of goods and services.

Money is therefore an extension of the barter system.

If There Was No Such Thing as Money… – Library of Rickandria

Barter is the act of trading something one possesses or does for something of someone else’s. 

Production and barter are the bases of all economy.

Coins and paper money were originally created to assist in barter.

They allowed people to barter without having to carry around actual goods or immediately deliver a service.

This permitted individuals to trade more easily and to save the profits of their labors for the future.

Paper money initially began as “promissory notes.”

A promissory note is a written promise to pay a debt.

A person would write a note on a piece of paper promising the bearer of the note a certain quantity of goods or services that the note writer could provide on demand.
 

To illustrate, let us look at the following fictitious example:


Let us pretend that a chicken farmer was in the village market and wanted to trade for a basket of apples.

He did not have his chickens with him, so he might write a note to the apple seller entitling the bearer of the note to come up to the farm at any time to pick out two healthy chickens.

The chicken farmer would be able to walk away with his basket of apples and it would be up to the apple grower to visit the farm one day to redeem the note by getting his two chickens.

As long as people have faith in the chicken farmer’s ability to honor his notes, he will be able to use them for barter.

Let us now pretend that as the day draws to a close, the apple grower decides to have a look around the market.

He comes across the cloth merchant.

The apple grower’s wife has been henpecking him for days to buy some of the new silk that just arrived on a caravan from the Far East.

Satanism: Far East Origins – Library of Rickandria

The apple grower’s home life has been made miserable by her unceasing demands and her denial of wifely comforts, so he negotiates with the cloth merchant for some silk.

The cloth merchant, however, does not need any more apples, so the apple grower, remembering that he has a note for two chickens, asks the merchant if the merchant needs poultry.

The merchant says that he does, and the apple grower gives him the note for two chickens in exchange for silk.

It is now up to the cloth merchant to trudge on up to the chicken farm to redeem the note.

The chickens themselves have never left the coop, yet they have changed ownership twice in one day.

This type of exchange was all that paper money was initially created for; but do you seethe temptation that it can open up?

If the chicken farmer knows that some time will pass before he must redeem his notes with actual chickens, or that some if his notes will circulate forever and never come in for redemption, he may be tempted to issue more notes than he has in actual chickens, thinking that he will be able to cover all the notes by the time they come back to him.

Temptation now gets the best of the chicken farmer.

The chicken farmer has a big family get-together coming up and he wants to impress his in-laws for once by putting on an opulent feast.

Down to the market he goes where he writes notes for chickens not yet hatched and stocks up with an abundance of goods from other merchants.

Several things can now happen.

The chicken farmer will get away with it if he is always able to meet the demand for chickens when his notes come in for redemption.

Another thing that may, and often will, occur is that he has so saturated the marketplace with his chicken notes that most people just do not want any more of them, so he must offer even more hens for each trade to make people feel that it is worth their while.

He is now writing notes for two or three chickens in exchange for items for which he previously only had to issue single-chicken notes.

As these chicken notes circulate, they become less and less valuable because there are so many of them.

A vicious spiral ensues: 


the more notes the chicken farmer issues, the less valuable they become, and the more he has to issue in order to get what he wants.

This is known as inflation.

Now comes the worst part.

With more and more notes outstanding, an increasing number of notes will start coming in for redemption.

Soon the farmer will see that his true wealth, which is his supply of chickens, is becoming rapidly depleted even though only a small portion of his outstanding notes have come back.

To preserve his chickens, he must decrease the value of his notes by declaring that the outstanding notes are now only good for half of what they say.

This is called devaluation.

Since the farmer may find it difficult to admit that he had issued many more notes than he had chickens, he may try to save his reputation by lying, such as by saying that a fierce chicken plague had wiped out half of his flock.

That will probably not prevent him from becoming very unpopular.

Public faith in his notes will be destroyed.

He will either have to revert back to straight barter, or else he will need to acquire someone else’s notes in order to continue trading in the market.

As we can see, paper notes, or money, are rooted in actual commodities and are meant to be an expression that the creator of the notes has something valuable to trade.

In contrast to notes are coins, which functioned somewhat differently.

Metals have always been considered valuable, and so pieces of metal were convenient trading tools.

Metal pieces were imprinted with various designs, thereby becoming coins, and their metallic purity was guaranteed by the imprinter.

Coin values were initially determined by the quantity and purity of the metal contained within the coins.

Gold was a rare and popular metal, so coins made from gold were more expensive and had a higher barter value than, for instance, copper coins.

Gold for Humans & Others… – Library of Rickandria

Metal coins became a popular tool of barter because they were durable, and quantities could be controlled.

They did create some problems, however.

Realistically, people were only trading pieces of metal for other goods.

This created a disproportionate emphasis on metals.

The acquisition of coins and coin metals became an obsession to a great many people, and such obsessions tend to drain away energy better spent producing other valuable goods and services.

The system also gave a disproportionate amount of power to those who possessed large quantities of coined metals, even though other commodities, such as food, are ultimately more valuable.

The person with the coin metals could immediately acquire any good or service, but a farmer first had to go through the intermediate step of exchanging his product for a coin or coin metal before he could have the same spending flexibility.

image.png 1.03 MB View full-size Download


Coin metals merged with paper notes to create the foundation of our modern monetary system in the 1600’s.

Those who laid this foundation were reportedly the goldsmiths.

Goldsmiths usually owned the strongest safes and lockboxes in town.

For this reason, many people deposited their coin metals with the smiths for safekeeping.

The smiths issued receipts to the depositors that promised to pay to the receipt holders on demand those quantities of gold or silver shown on the receipts.

Every such receipt was actually a note which could be circulated as money until a holder of the note went back to the goldsmith to redeem it for the specified amount of metal.

The goldsmiths made an important discovery.

Under normal circumstances, only about 10% to 20% of their receipts ever came back for redemption at any given time.

The rest circulated in the community as money, and for good reason.

Paper was easier to carry than bulky coin and people felt safer holding receipts in lieu of actual gold and silver.

The smiths realized that they could lend out the unredeemed metals and charge interest, and thereby earn money as lenders.

In making such a loan, however, the smith would try to convince the borrower to accept the loan in the form of a receipt instead of actual metal.

The borrower could then circulate that note as money.

As we can see, the goldsmith has now created “money” (his receipts) for double the actual quantity of metal he has in his safe: 


first to the original depositor, and then to a borrower.

The goldsmith did not even own the metal in his safe, yet by simply writing upon a piece of paper, someone now owes him money up to the full value of the gold in his safe.

The smith could continue writing his notes as long as the notes coming in for redemption did not exceed his actual deposits of precious metals.

Typically, a smith would issue notes four to five times in excess of his actual supply of gold.

As profitable as this operation may have been, there were some pitfalls.

If too many of the goldsmith’s notes came back for redemption too rapidly, or the smith’s borrowers were slow to repay, the smith would be wiped out.

The credibility of his notes would be destroyed.

If the smith ran his operation cautiously, however, he could become quite wealthy without ever producing anything of value.

The injustice of this system is obvious.

If for every sack of gold, the smith had on deposit people now owed him the equivalent of four sacks, someone had to lose.

As public debt to the goldsmith increased, more and more true wealth and resources were owed to him.

Since the goldsmith was not producing any true wealth or resources but was demanding an ever-increasing share of them because of his paper notes, he easily became a parasite upon the economy.

The inevitable result was the enrichment of the careful goldsmith-turned-banker at the cost of the impoverishment of other people in the community.
 
That impoverishment was manifested either in the people’s need to give up things of value or in their need to toil longer to create the wealth needed to repay the banker.

If the goldsmith was not careful and his monetary bubble burst, the people around him suffered anyway due to the disruption caused by the collapse of his bank and the loss of the value of his notes still in circulation.

Such was the birth of modern banking.

Global Banking System – Library of Rickandria

Many people feel that it is an inherently dishonest system.

It is.

It is also socially and economically destabilizing, yet all of the world’s major monetary and banking systems today operate on a close variation of the system I just described.

By the 17th century, the Medici banking house of Italy had come up with the idea of using gold as the commodity upon which to base all paper currency.

Philip III the Bold & the Crusades – Library of Rickandria

Gold was touted as the perfect basis for paper notes because of the scarcity and desirability of gold.

This was the beginning of the “gold standard” in which all other goods and services are valued in relation to gold (and sometimes silver).
 
The gold standard was certainly a terrific idea for those people who owned plenty of gold and silver, but it created an artificial reliance on a commodity that is not nearly as useful as many other products.

To base an entire monetary system on a single commodity is better than basing it upon no commodities at all, but even under a gold standard paper notes will far exceed the metals used to back the notes.

The best solution is to root a money supply firmly in a nation’s entire valuable output so that the money acts as an accurate reflection of that output.

Once the gold standard was created, paper notes were thought to be “as good as gold” because people could redeem the notes for actual gold.

This created a false sense of security.

As more and more gold notes entered the market, they gradually became worth less and less, resulting in a steady inflation.

The gold owners/bankers had to keep issuing a constant stream of notes because that is how they earned their profits.
 
As long as the bankers planned carefully and the people retained faith in the notes, the note writers could stay ahead of the inevitable inflation they created and make an enormous profit from it.

If, on the other hand, they issued an overabundance and too many of their notes came back for redemption, they could, as a last resort, devalue the notes to save their gold.

In this fashion, inflatable paper money, even under a gold standard, became a source of wealth and power to those entitled to create the money.

It also generated indebtedness on an enormous scale because most of the “created-out-of-nothing” gold notes were released into the community as loans repayable to the bankers.

If people did not borrow from the bankers, little new money would enter the market and the economy would slow down.

This method of creating money clearly destroyed the true purpose of money: 


to represent the existence of actual tradable commodities.

Inflatable paper money allows a handful of people to absorb and manipulate a great deal of true wealth, which are the valuable goods and services people produce, simply through the act of printing paper and then slowly destroying the value of that paper with inflation.

It causes money to become its own commodity which can be manipulated on its own terms, usually to the detriment of the production-and-barter system.

Money was meant to assist that system, not to dominate and control it.

The inflatable paper money system described above was the new “science” of money being installed by Brotherhood revolutionaries.

An early version of the system was established in Holland in 1609.

That was the year in which Dutch and Spanish forces signed a truce suspending the hostilities of the Eighty Years War.

The truce marked the birth of the independent Dutch Republic and the founding of the Bank of Amsterdam in the same year.

The privately-owned Bank of Amsterdam operated on the inflatable paper money system described above.

It was run by a group of financiers who pooled some of their precious metals to form the asset base of the Bank.

By prior agreement with the new Dutch government, the Bank helped Dutch forces resume the wars against Spain by issuing notes four times in excess of the Bank’s asset base.

The Dutch magistrates were then able to draw on three quarters of the “created-out-of-nothing” money to finance the conflict.
 

This reveals the primary reason why the inflatable paper money system was created: 


it enables nations to fight and prolong their wars. It also makes the human struggle for physical existence in a modern economy more difficult due to the massive debt and parasitic absorption of wealth that the system causes.

Furthermore, steady inflation reduces the value of people’s money so that their accumulated weal this gradually eroded.

The Custodial aims expressed in the Garden of Eden and Tower of Babel stories were greatly furthered by the new paper money system.

The initial success of the Bank of Amsterdam encouraged similar banking arrangements in other nations.

The most notable offspring was the Bank of England, founded in1694.

The Bank of England established the pattern for our modern-day central banks by refining the inflatable paper money system of Holland.

The Bank of England system was subsequently spread from nation to nation, often on the backs of revolutions led by prominent Brotherhood network members.
 
The worldwide reformation announced in the Fama Fraternitas was well underway by the end of the 17th century, and the “new money” was a big part of it, as we shall see more of later.

Fama Fraternitas – Library of Rickandria


The Gods of Eden - Chapter 21: Funny Money (basecamp.com)


The Gods of Eden – Chapter 21: Funny Money – Library of Rickandria